Chapter XXIX

The carrying out of Levin’s plan presented
many difficulties; but he struggled on, doing his utmost, and
attained a result which, though not what he desired, was enough to
enable him, without self-deception, to believe that the attempt was
worth the trouble. One of the chief difficulties was that the
process of cultivating the land was in full swing, that it was
impossible to stop everything and begin it all again from the
beginning, and the machine had to be mended while in motion.
When on the evening that he arrived home he
informed the bailiff of his plans, the latter with visible pleasure
agreed with what he said so long as he was pointing out that all
that had been done up to that time was stupid and useless. The
bailiff said that he had said so a long while ago, but no heed had
been paid him. But as for the proposal made by Levin—to take a part
as shareholder with his laborers in each agricultural
undertaking—at this the bailiff simply expressed a profound
despondency, and offered no definite opinion, but began immediately
talking of the urgent necessity of carrying the remaining sheaves
of rye the next day, and of sending the men out for the second
ploughing, so that Levin felt that this was not the time for
discussing it.
On beginning to talk to the peasants about it, and
making a proposition to cede them the land on new terms, he came
into collision with the same great difficulty that they were so
much absorbed by the current work of the day, that they had not
time to consider the advantages and disadvantages of the proposed
scheme.
The simple-hearted Ivan, the cowherd, seemed
completely to grasp Levin’s proposal—that he should with his family
take a share of the profits of the cattle-yard-and he was in
complete sympathy with the plan. But when Levin hinted at the
future advantages, Ivan’s face expressed alarm and regret that he
could not hear all he had to say, and he made haste to find himself
some task that would admit of no delay: he either snatched up the
fork to pitch the hay out of the pens, or ran to get water or to
clear out the dung.
Another difficulty lay in the invincible disbelief
of the peasant that a landowner’s object could be anything else
than a desire to squeeze all he could out of them. They were firmly
convinced that his real aim (whatever he might say to them) would
always be in what he did not say to them. And they themselves, in
giving their opinion, said a great deal but never said what was
their real object. Moreover (Levin felt that the irascible
landowner had been right) the peasants made their first and
unalterable condition of any agreement whatever that they should
not be forced to any new methods of tillage of any kind, nor to use
new implements. They agreed that the modern plough ploughed better,
that the scarifier did the work more quickly, but they found
thousands of reasons that made it out of the question for them to
use either of them; and though he had accepted the conviction that
he would have to lower the standard of cultivation, he felt sorry
to give up improved methods, the advantages of which were so
obvious. But in spite of all these difficulties he got his way, and
by autumn the system was working, or at least so it seemed to
him.
At first Levin had thought of giving up the whole
farming of the land just as it was to the peasants, the laborers,
and the bailiff on new conditions of partnership; but he was very
soon convinced that this was impossible, and determined to divide
it up. The cattle-yard, the garden, hay-fields, and arable land,
divided into several parts, had to be made into separate lots. The
simple-hearted cowherd, Ivan, who, Levin fancied, understood the
matter better than any of them, collecting together a gang of
workers to help him, principally of his own family, became a
partner in the cattle-yard. A distant part of the estate, a tract
of waste land that had lain fallow for eight years, was with the
help of the clever carpenter, Fyodor Ryezunov, taken by six
families of peasants on new conditions of partnership, and the
peasant Shuraev took the management of all the vegetable gardens on
the same terms. The remainder of the land was still worked on the
old system, but these three associated partnerships were the first
step to a new organization of the whole, and they completely took
up Levin’s time.
It is true that in the cattle-yard things went no
better than before, and Ivan strenuously opposed warm housing for
the cows and butter made of fresh cream, affirming that cows
require less food if kept cold, and that butter is more profitable
made from sour cream, and he asked for wages just as under the old
system, and took not the slightest interest in the fact that the
money he received was not wages but an advance out of his future
share in the profits.
It is true that Fyodor Ryezunov’s company did not
plough over the ground twice before sowing, as had been agreed,
justifying themselves on the plea that the time was too short. It
is true that the peasants of the same company, though they had
agreed to work the land on new conditions, always spoke of the
land, not as held in partnership, but as rented for half the crop,
and more than once the peasants and Ryezunov himself said to Levin,
“If you would take a rent for the land, it would save you trouble,
and we should be more free.” Moreover the same peasants kept
putting off, on various excuses, the building of a cattle-yard and
barn on the land as agreed upon, and delayed doing it till the
winter.
It is true that Shuraev would have liked to let out
the kitchen gardens he had undertaken in small lots to the
peasants, He evidently quite misunderstood, and apparently
intentionally misunderstood, the conditions upon which the land had
been given to him.
Often, too, talking to the peasants and explaining
to them all the advantages of the plan, Levin felt that the
peasants heard nothing but the sound of his voice, and were firmly
resolved, whatever he might say, not to let themselves be taken in.
He felt this especially when he talked to the cleverest of the
peasants, Ryezunov, and detected the gleam in Ryezunov’s eyes which
showed so plainly both ironical amusement at Levin, and the firm
conviction that, if any one were to be taken in, it would not be
he, Ryezunov. But in spite of all this Levin thought the system
worked, and that by keeping accounts strictly and insisting on his
own way, he would prove to them in the future the advantages of the
arrangement, and then the system would go of itself.
These matters, together with the management of the
land still left on his hands, and the indoor work over his book, so
engrossed Levin the whole summer that he scarcely ever went out
shooting. At the end of August he heard that the Oblonskys had gone
away to Moscow, from their servant who brought back the
side-saddle. He felt that in not answering Darya Alexandrovna’s
letter he had by his rudeness, of which he could not think without
a flush of shame, burned his ships, and that he would never go and
see them again. He had been just as rude with the Sviazhskys,
leaving them without saying good-bye. But he would never go to see
them again either. He did not care about that now. The business of
reorganizing the farming of his land absorbed him as completely as
though there would never be anything else in his life. He read the
books lent him by Sviazhsky, and copying out what he had not got,
he read both the economic and socialistic books on the subject,
but, as he had anticipated, found nothing bearing on the scheme he
had undertaken. In the books on political economy—in Mill,1 for
instance, whom he studied first with great ardor, hoping every
minute to find an answer to the questions that were engrossing
him—he found laws deduced from the condition of land culture in
Europe; but he did not see why these laws, which did not apply in
Russia, must be general. He saw just the same thing in the
socialistic books: either they were the beautiful but impracticable
fantasies which had fascinated him when he was a student, or they
were attempts at improving, rectifying the economic position in
which Europe was placed, with which the system of land tenure in
Russia had nothing in common. Political economy told him that the
laws by which the wealth of Europe had been developed, and was
developing, were universal and unvarying. Socialism told him that
development along these lines leads to ruin. And neither of them
gave an answer, or even a hint, in reply to the question what he,
Levin, and all the Russian peasants and landowners, were to do with
their millions of hands and millions of acres, to make them as
productive as possible for the common weal.
Having once taken the subject up, he read
conscientiously everything bearing on it, and intended in the
autumn to go abroad to study land systems on the spot, in order
that he might not on this question be confronted with what so often
met him on various subjects. Often, just as he was beginning to
understand the idea in the mind of any one he was talking to, and
was beginning to explain his own, he would suddenly be told: “But
Kauffmann, but Jones, but Dubois, but Michelli?2
You haven’t read them: they’ve thrashed that question out
thoroughly.”
He saw now distinctly that Kauffmann and Michelli
had nothing to tell him. He knew what he wanted. He saw that Russia
has splendid land, splendid laborers, and that in certain cases, as
at the peasant’s on the way to Sviazhsky’s, the produce raised by
the laborers and the land is great—in the majority of cases when
capital is applied in the European way the produce is small, and
that this simply arises from the fact that the laborers want to
work and work well only in their own peculiar way, and that this
antagonism is not incidental but invariable, and has its roots in
the national spirit. He thought that the Russian people whose task
it was to colonize and cultivate vast tracts of unoccupied land,
consciously adhered, till all their land was occupied, to the
methods suitable to their purpose, and that their methods were by
no means so bad as was generally supposed. And he wanted to prove
this theoretically in his book and practically on his land.