FOUR
A“ Court Always Leads to Something”
(1816-1825)
You are certainly right that there is much to
be earned from a government which has no money. But you have to
take risks.
—JAMES ROTHSCHILD TO NATHAN ROTHSCHILD.
—NATHAN ROTHSCHILD TO CHRISTIAN ROTHER.
In 1823 the twelfth, thirteenth and fourteenth
cantos of Byron’s Don Juan were published in London, at a time when
their author was embroiled—fatally, as it proved—in the Greek
struggle for independence. Byron’s aristocratic profligacy with
money was by now as notorious as his libertinism. Nevertheless,
these late verses indicate a keen awareness of the power of
money—and specifically of the new kind of financial power
personified by Nathan Rothschild. “Who hold the balance of the
world?” asked Byron in the twelfth canto, “Who reign
O’er Congress, whether royalist or liberal?
Who rouse the shirtless patriots of Spain?
(That make old Europe’s journals squeak and gibber all.)
Who keep the world, both old and new, in pain
Or pleasure? Who make politics run glibber all?
The shade of Bonaparte’s noble daring? -
Jew Rothschild, and his fellow Christian Baring.1
Who rouse the shirtless patriots of Spain?
(That make old Europe’s journals squeak and gibber all.)
Who keep the world, both old and new, in pain
Or pleasure? Who make politics run glibber all?
The shade of Bonaparte’s noble daring? -
Jew Rothschild, and his fellow Christian Baring.1
Those lines have been quoted by historians before.
It is worth, however, reading the verse which follows too, for it
nicely illustrates the ambivalent feelings with which
contemporaries regarded the spectacular financial boom of the early
1820s. To Byron, Rothschild and Baring were, along with the “truly
liberal Laffitte,” “the true Lords of Europe,” whose every loan
Is not a merely speculative hit,
But seats a nation or upsets a throne.
Republics also get involved a bit;
Columbia’s stock hath holders not unknown
On ’Change; and even thy silver soil, Peru,
Must get itself discounted by a Jew.
But seats a nation or upsets a throne.
Republics also get involved a bit;
Columbia’s stock hath holders not unknown
On ’Change; and even thy silver soil, Peru,
Must get itself discounted by a Jew.
Byron went on to discuss—with remarkable
insight—that ascetic materialism which, as we have seen, was such a
distinctive early Rothschild trait. Indeed, it seems not
unreasonable to suggest that the poet’s reflections on “gaunt
Wealth’s austerities” may have been inspired by Nathan himself:
He is your only poet;—passion, pure
And sparkling on from heap to heap, displays
Possess’d, the ore, of which mere hopes allure
Nations athwart the deep: the golden rays
Flash up in ingots from the mine obscure;
On him the diamond pours its brilliant blaze,
While the mild emerald’s beam shades down the dyes
Of other stones, to soothe the miser’s eyes.
And sparkling on from heap to heap, displays
Possess’d, the ore, of which mere hopes allure
Nations athwart the deep: the golden rays
Flash up in ingots from the mine obscure;
On him the diamond pours its brilliant blaze,
While the mild emerald’s beam shades down the dyes
Of other stones, to soothe the miser’s eyes.
The lands on either side are his: the ship
From Ceylon, Inde, or far Cathay, unloads
For him the fragrant produce of each trip;
Beneath his cars of Ceres groan the roads,
And the vine blushes like Aurora’s lip;
His very cellars might be kings’ abodes;
While he, despising every sensual call,
Commands—the intellectual lord of all.
From Ceylon, Inde, or far Cathay, unloads
For him the fragrant produce of each trip;
Beneath his cars of Ceres groan the roads,
And the vine blushes like Aurora’s lip;
His very cellars might be kings’ abodes;
While he, despising every sensual call,
Commands—the intellectual lord of all.
Perhaps he hath great projects in his mind,
To build a college, or to found a race,
A hospital, a church,—and leave behind
Some dome surmounted by his meagre face:
Perhaps he fain would liberate mankind
Even with the very ore which makes them base:
Perhaps he would be wealthiest of his nation,
Or revel in the joys of calculation.
To build a college, or to found a race,
A hospital, a church,—and leave behind
Some dome surmounted by his meagre face:
Perhaps he fain would liberate mankind
Even with the very ore which makes them base:
Perhaps he would be wealthiest of his nation,
Or revel in the joys of calculation.
The allusion to “his nation” may indicate that
there was more of Rothschild than of Baring in this inspired
evocation of financial might.
That Byron could suggest—even satirically—that
Nathan Rothschild held, along with Alexander Baring, “the balance
of the world” requires some explanation. The name of Baring was, of
course, well established. Like the Rothschilds the family hailed
from Germany (Francis Baring had emigrated from Bremen in 1717);
and, like Nathan, Francis’s son John had made his fortune in the
textiles business, as a wool manufacturer, before his sons
established the merchant bank of Baring Brothers in 1770. However,
as Lutherans the Barings had easily been absorbed into the social
elite of Exeter and later London. John’s younger son Francis had
been an MP since 1784, a member of the board of the East India
Company since 1779 and a baronet since 1793. Alexander, his son and
successor at the bank, also became an MP in 1806. By contrast, only
a few years before Don Juan, the Rothschilds’ role in the
financing of the war against Napoleon was still largely a secret,
known only to political and financial insiders. Even the Paris
banker Jacques Laffitte was better known as Governor of the Banque
de France between 1814 and 1820 and one of Napoleon’s financial
backers in the Hundred Days. What happened in the years after the
upheaval of Waterloo to catapult Nathan to such celebrity—and
notoriety—that he could be said to “reign” over royalists and
liberals, “rouse” Spanish patriots and “keep the world, both old
and new, in pain / Or pleasure?”
The Economic Consequences of the
Peace
The answer must be sought in what might be called
(to adapt a phrase used in similar circumstances a century later)
the economic consequences of the peace—the Second Peace of Paris,
imposed on France after Waterloo. The First Treaty of Paris had
imposed no reparations on the restored Bourbon regime, but the mood
of the victorious powers after Waterloo was less clement. Quite
apart from any desire to punish the French collectively for the
actions of those who had rallied to Napoleon in the Hundred Days,
there was a practical need to pay for the troops occupying northern
France, who at one stage numbered more than a million. Even before
the peace was signed in November, a charge or “contribution” of
some 50 million francs was levied to pay for their upkeep. The
final terms of the treaty set a total for reparations of 700
million francs to be paid over five years beginning in March 1816,
during which time an occupying force of 150,000 men would remain on
French soil. The costs of this occupation were also to be met by
the French Treasury.2
The Rothschilds evidently hoped that the financial
provisions of the peace—which implied a new and potentially
lucrative series of international transfers, this time from Paris
rather than London—would provide them with plentiful opportunities
to recoup the losses of the Hundred Days. At first, there were
grounds for optimism, at least as far as relations with the
recipient states were concerned. Gervais as usual promised to hand
Rothschilds the better part of Russia’s share, and Herries was
likewise expected to secure a large tranche of the British.
However, it quickly became apparent that any business arising from
the French “contributions” would have to be shared with other
bankers, who now rushed to challenge the Rothschild monopoly on
international transfer payments. Only by entering into loose
partnerships—with Mendelssohn in Berlin, Bethmann and Gontard in
Frankfurt, Arnstein & Eskeles in Vienna and Parish & Co. in
Hamburg—were Salomon and James able to participate in the initial
payments to Prussia and Austria. Even the British and Russian
contributions could not be taken for granted.
Partly, the problem was one of declining influence.
Dunmore, Herries’s representative in Paris, was less “friendly”
than Herries himself, while the Russian minister Count Nesselrode
had reasons for favouring Gontard. It was a serious setback when
first Gervais and then Herries left office. To make matters worse,
some of the other officials they found themselves dealing with—the
Russian Merian and the Prussian Rother—declined to accept bribes.
But the real problem was that peace had brought competition. As
James complained, contemplating profits of 1.5 per cent and less,
there was “not much joy to be had from the contributions business,
because there are too many people here.” Salomon was especially
irked by the Austrian representatives, who “run from one house to
the next for the sake of an extra sou.” Ultimately, he and James
became almost fatalistic: “There are no big, brilliant deals to be
made here. But now that we’re here, we’re happy to take all that we
can to prevent it going to anyone else.” The only consoling
thought—frequently repeated—was that contacts with courts, no
matter how unprofitable, might lead to business in the future. The
brothers never turned up their noses at small-scale transactions
and gladly advanced the contributions due to the smaller German
states and the minor compensation payments which Russia had to make
for damage to private property by Russian troops.
Far more disappointing, however, was James’s
failure to win a share of the business generated on the other side
of the reparations equation. That France would be able to pay
reparations and the costs of occupation only by means of a large
loan had become obvious by late 1816. Despite efforts to cut
spending and raise taxes, there was no realistic way of achieving
an annual surplus in excess of 170 million francs, not least
because of the unhelpful attitude of the ultra-royalist “Incredible
Chamber” which—like most nineteenth-century assemblies elected by
income or property tax payers—showed little enthusiasm for raising
direct taxes. Indeed, the 1816-17 budget showed a deficit of over
300 million francs, which was financed only with the greatest
difficulty by short-term borrowing. Moreover, the Paris capital
market by itself was far too weak to absorb unassisted the new
issues of rentes which were inevitably going to be needed. With the
price of 5 per cent rentes down as low as 50, the government had
little option but to look abroad.
In the immediate aftermath of Napoleon’s defeat,
the Rothschilds’ prospects of influence at the French court had
been good. Not only had they been responsible for relaying a
British loan to the returning French King, but Dalberg, the former
Prince-Primate of Napoleon’s Rhenish Confederation and Grand Duke
of Frankfurt, had emerged as a member of the French provisional
government—one of a number of opportunists (the most famous being
Talleyrand) who managed to survive yet another change of regime by
a well-timed defection.3 However, the resignation of Talleyrand
and the formation of a new government under the duc de Richelieu
appear to have weakened the Rothschild position. James made every
effort to cultivate Richelieu’s secretary, who evidently provided
valuable inside information on French intentions. But, when the
question of a loan was raised in the autumn and winter of 1816, the
Finance Minister Corvetto elected to give the business to Baring
and Pierre-César Labouchère of Hope & Co.,4 who had successfully been wooed by
Gabriel-Julien Ouvrard, another survivor of the imperial era. An
agreement was reached in early 1817 whereby, in return for a 2.5
per cent commission, Baring provided the French government with an
initial 297 million francs in return for 5 per cent rentes. Because
the bonds were issued over a period of several months in three
tranches at prices of 52.5, 55.5 and 61.5, this meant that the
French government had increased its national debt by around 534
million francs for the sake of less than 300 million francs in
cash—or to put it another way, it was paying interest at an
effective rate of around 9 per cent, nearly double the nominal rate
on its rentes. Contrary to later mythology, the Rothschilds found
themselves more or less excluded from this immense operation, “to
prevent,” so Baring claimed, “a selling race at the exchanges with
resulting depreciation.”
This was a bitter blow to James, who had expended
considerable energy on his own plans for a loan, and who believed
up until the eleventh hour that, at the very least, he would be
able to participate in some kind of consortium. “Depressed” and
angry, he railed at Baring’s duplicity, claiming that his rival had
bribed the French government to exaggerate its inability to pay and
thereby secure a six-month breathing-space. His anger was redoubled
when a last-ditch effort (in partnership with Laffitte and Parish)
to join the Baring group for the third issue of rentes in July 1817
came to nothing. Salomon, returning to Paris from London, could not
help but admire the way his brother had been outmanoeuvred:
He is quite a crook this Baring. Today he is going
to dine with us, together with Laffitte . . . We must certainly
watch our step as far as he is concerned. Baring’s lot are and were
as well versed in the way of using influence as we are. There is
not a single man of importance amongst the authorities here who
would not work with Baring hand in glove . . . The Russian
ambassador Pozzo di Borgo is on the side of France and of Baring
whose orbit he is in . . . Baring and the French Minister of
Finances are sharing the profit. The Minister is reputed to be one
of the most corrupt of all.
Whatever the truth of these allegations, Baring was
in a strong enough position to exclude James again when the
negotiations began for a final loan to pay off the remainder of the
indemnity. Although rentes with a face value of 290 million francs
were issued directly to the public in May 1818, the government
appears to have taken fright at the frantic speculation these
attracted (the issue was oversubscribed almost ten times, pushing
prices up to a peak of 80 compared with an issue price of 66.5),
and a second issue of 480 million francs (nominal) in the same
month was entrusted to Baring. When James—along with the other
Paris banks Baguenault, Delessert, Greffulhe, Hottinguer and
Laffitte—was offered a mere 10 million francs, to be shared with
David Parish, he was disgusted, fulminating at the “abominable” way
he had been treated. He and the others had to content themselves
with shares of a 31 million franc loan to the city of Paris. As the
Duke of Wellington reported to Lord Liverpool, “The fact is that
Baring, having the French finances in his hands, and French loans
being in fashion in England, has to a certain degree the command of
the money market of the world. He feels his power, and it is not a
very easy task to succeed in counteracting him.” If there was ever
a moment when Barings deserved to be called “the sixth great power”
(a probably apocryphal phrase attributed to Richelieu), then this
was it.
There were admittedly arguments for limiting the
brothers’ direct involvement in a large-scale loan to France. After
the trauma of the Hundred Days, Nathan had good reason to doubt the
stability of the restored Bourbon regime. Salomon might reassure
him that, according to best sources in Paris, there would be “no
more revolution in France,” but he added the important rider: “at
least not in the foreseeable future, and if there is something, it
is certainly not be feared in the next three months.” After all, as
he admitted, there was “no way of insuring against the hot heads of
the French,” and a future default could not be ruled out. Such
comments suggest that he had no more confidence than Nathan in
French funds. This pessimism was reinforced by “talk of war” which
James heard in Paris in May 1816. A few months later he was even
more alarmed by news that the British government might favour
replacing Louis XVIII with the duc d’Orléans, which James warned
would lead to civil war. Widespread social unrest in 1817 caused by
a bad harvest and high food prices reinforced such anxieties.
On the other hand, the financial position of the
restored Bourbon regime was less shaky than it appeared, and this
helps explain the rapid rise in the price of rentes during 1817 and
the first half of 1818 which made the loan so profitable for its
contractors. Because of the great assignat inflation of the 1790s,
France—unlike Britain—had more or less wiped out the accumulated
debts of the eighteenth century. Its total public debt in 1815
stood at just 1.2 billion francs, roughly 10 per cent of national
income—so much less than the equivalent figure for Britain that it
amounted to a clean slate. It was therefore easy, once Baring had
started the ball rolling, for France to issue further loans without
in any way depressing the price of rentes. As the price of rentes
rose, Baring was getting, as James ruefully observed, “money for
nothing.” France’s resources were in reality “formidable” and the
political situation stable: “If the Allies withdraw, France will
remain quiet. Be assured that there is no party left here which
could put up resistance to the Government, at least not
soon.”
The Rothschilds’ failure to secure the 1817 and
1818 reparations loans was therefore a costly defeat. The
implication was clear: if they had stolen a march on other bankers
in early 1814, now they had to face a determined effort by the
Barings and Bethmanns to reclaim their earlier predominance in
European public finance, as well as new competition from less
established figures like Gontard and the Bavarian financier Adolph
d’Eichthal.5 As Carl had put it in 1814, “The main
thing is that people are hostile towards us because we have the
business.” “We have enemies aplenty,” James lamented a year later,
“though it is more a matter of envy than enmity. Every five minutes
someone else is going to the [Prussian] minister and asks: ‘Why
does Rothschild get given everything?’ ” It had been easier before,
commented Carl, when the risks were greater, because there had been
less competition. Indeed, James even acknowledged that, in seeking
to exclude them from the reparations payments, the Viennese bankers
were only “doing what the Rothschilds had done” over the subsidies.
Baring seemed to pose the biggest threat at this stage. Not only
did he and his associates “want to subject all of France according
to their will so that they can do what they like”; they also posed
a threat to Nathan’s position in London. As Amschel said, Nathan
seemed to be “rather upset if somebody else does any business
transactions with London. He feels that he more or less owns
London.” It cannot have pleased him to hear it said “that [because
of Baring] you don’t play any longer the first [role] on the Stock
Exchange and that you are unable to fix the quotation” of stocks.
However, the growth of competition was just as marked in smaller
financial markets like Kassel, where the end of the war and the
return of the Elector led to frenetic efforts to end the
Rothschilds’ near-monopoly over his finances, built up during his
years in exile, and to win a share of the Rothschilds’ “mountains
of gold.”6 As James put it in early 1818, “The
whole world is jealous.”
The Rothschilds did not suffer competitors gladly.
Indeed, they had a wide range of abusive terms for them, such as
Schurken (scoundrels), Bösewichte (rogues) and
Spitzbuben (rascals). Even before Waterloo, there had been
much talk of “putting spokes in wheels” of rival “scoundrels” and
“sharpshooters,” and dealing them “blows where it hurts.” The
question in 1818 was how best to “hurt” Baring and Labouchère.
Tradition has it that the brothers did so by means of a huge
intervention in the market for rentes. First, they invested heavily
in the new rentes being created under the Baring scheme. Then, just
as the great powers met at Aix-la-Chapelle to negotiate the final
reparations payments, they allegedly turned from bulls into bears,
dumping rentes on the market with devastating consequences for
prices. In this way, they decisively weakened Baring’s position,
forcing him to call off the final loan which he had been on the
point of making on behalf of France. There is no doubt that we need
an explanation for the remarkable speed with which the Rothschilds
outstripped their more established rivals. And it is true that
Baring was acutely embarrassed by the sharp drop in rentes to a
nadir of 60, and was saved only by the fact that so many of the
ministers present at Aix—including Nesselrode, the Austrian
Chancellor Prince Metternich and his Prussian counterpart Prince
Hardenberg—had themselves taken shares, and therefore had a common
interest in cancelling the final loan.7 However, no archival evidence has come
to light to support the notion that the Rothschilds were directly
responsible for the crisis.
The brothers undoubtedly sought to join in the bull
run in the French bond market after 1816. James held rentes worth 3
million francs (nominal) at the beginning of March 1817, and by the
end of the month he had acquired a further 7 million, all bought on
the assumption of a sustained rise. Soon he was inundated with
orders to purchase rentes for Nathan and his London relatives too,
though he himself still felt “in the dark” as to how long the rise
could be sustained. It also seems quite likely, as Ouvrard later
claimed, that James took advantage of the system of part-payment to
maximise his speculative purchases. But there is no evidence of a
concerted policy of selling at any time in 1818. When James did
take profits, he took care that his sales should not be noticed,
precisely to avoid weakening the market as a whole; and when rentes
did weaken in the summer of 1817, the brothers actually made
purchases to support the market. Indeed, it is from this period
that we can date that keen preoccupation with the health of the
rente, and any news which might affect it, which was to be a
feature of his correspondence for the next fifty years. A year
later, in July 1818, he saw no reason to question Laffitte and
Delessert’s assumption that rentes would reach par by the end of
the year.
None of this should surprise us. The Rothschilds
would have been taking a grave risk if they had sought to subvert
the final “liquidation” of the French indemnity. In February 1818
Salomon explicitly argued against an attack on Baring: it would be
counter-productive if people were able to say, “The Rothschilds
organised a diversion, the loan fell through, the troops can’t be
withdrawn.” In any case, Baring was an MP and had already asked
enough awkward questions about Herries’s activities as
Commissary-in-Chief. There were good reasons not to antagonise him.
The best explanation for the downturn in the price of rentes during
the Aix conference in fact lies in the policy of the Banque de
France, which had fuelled the surge in rente prices after May by
lending over-generously to the Paris banks. When a run on its
reserves alerted the Banque to its mistake, it over-compensated by
tightening its discounting terms. It was this contraction on the
money market which temporarily halted the speculation in rentes and
depressed prices. Once the Banque had been persuaded to relax its
policy again, rentes recovered rapidly, though it was not until
1821 (with prices at 87) that sufficient confidence had been
recovered to float the final reparations loan. Moreover, if the
Rothschilds had hoped to benefit from Baring’s retreat from the
French market, they were disappointed: the 1821 loan went to the
Paris bankers Hottinguer, Delessert and Baguenault.
In reality, it was British consols, not French
rentes, which the Rothschilds sold, and they did so at the end of
1817, not in late 1818—making a profit in the process which more
than compensated for any losses they may have suffered in the
summer of 1815. As we have seen, at the end of that year Nathan
had, at Herries’s recommendation, made substantial purchases of 3
per cent consols at prices of 61.1 and 61.5 as well as £450,000 of
Omnium stocks at 107. Throughout 1816 he ignored his nervous
brothers’ repeated advice to take profits, so that by the end of
that year he held altogether £1.2 million (nominal) worth of
consols. This must have been very nearly equivalent to the entire
capital of the firm. Family opinion on this strategy was divided:
cautious as ever, Amschel regarded it as “stupid . . . to invest
one’s whole fortune in one single security” and continued to urge
that Nathan sell, especially as he and Carl found themselves
increasingly strapped for cash in Frankfurt. James was more
enthusiastic—as he said, this single investment had already earned
them “as much as a loan”—but he questioned Nathan’s assessment that
consols would reach 80, and by April 1817 he too was urging a halt.
Those closer to New Court, however, joined in Nathan’s “spec” with
their own private savings. Caroline, Salomon’s wife, had evidently
caught the bug while staying with her brother-in-law: by August
1816, she was actually having dreams about consol prices reaching
86!—a revealing insight into the indirect participation of the
Rothschild women in the family business in this period. In May of
1817, when the upward trend was momentarily checked, Nathan finally
gave in to his brothers’ pleas by selling around £600,000, but he
evidently did so with the greatest reluctance and moved quickly to
reinvest even more before the rise resumed the following month. By
July, with consols leaping to above 82 and a total holding of £1.6
million (nominal), Salomon had to acknowledge that his brother had
pulled off another business “masterwork.”
It was at this point that Nathan began to sell,
realising profits of more than £250,000. Interestingly, this was
five months ahead of the market’s final peak at 84.25 in December
1817 (see illustration 4.i) and this may explain why he delayed
slightly before relaying the advice to sell to others. Even his
brothers-in-law and his oldest client in the market, the Elector of
Hesse-Kassel, were not tipped off until after Nathan had sold. As
it became apparent that the market had indeed peaked—by 1820 prices
were back below 70—Moses Montefiore hailed his brother-in-law’s
coup:
I am very happy to learn you make as good a Bear
as you formerly did a Bull, you must have had some difficulty with
my brother Abraham, indeed it is quite a new character for both . .
. You have beaten your antagonists so frequently that I am
surprised there are any so hardy to be found in the Stock Exchange
to oppose you in any considerable operation.
There is no simple explanation for the
Rothschilds’ triumph over their rivals in the 1820s: but this great
coup undoubtedly played an important part.
What had made Nathan decide to dispose of his
consols at the end of 1817? Part of the reason may have been a
premature alarm sounded by his brothers in Paris about the
possibility of war over Spain: not for the last time, the brothers
interpreted any threat of armed conflict between the great powers
as an argument for selling government bonds. But of greater
importance was the invaluable inside information he was receiving
about changes in British fiscal and monetary policy. This was the
fruit of Nathan’s growing proximity to the Chancellor of the
Exchequer, Nicholas Vansittart, as well as his brothers’ first
direct contacts with the Duke of Wellington—“old Stiff-back”—in
Paris. As the Rothschilds hastened to point out, it was not only
they but the British government too which had benefited from the
rise in consols. The surplus funds in the military chest which had
been left over after Napoleon’s defeat had also been used to
purchase £650,000 (nominal) of consols at 62 in 1816. Now that
consols stood at over 82, the Treasury stood to make a profit of
around £130,000. This good turn was clearly felt to deserve
another: Nathan was tipped off about a funding operation—involving
the issue of £27 million in new 3.5 or 3.25 per cent government
stocks—which was bound to depress the market for 3 per cents. As
Salomon’s letters at this time show, it was this inside information
more than anything else which determined Nathan’s move:
Vansittart is a very fine man, insofar as he gave
you a hint of a forthcoming funding operation. He well knows that
you were the only one who drove up the stocks, who lifted England’s
credit, and that you are the great holder of stocks . . . Now it is
time to work out a plan. We agree with you that in the case of a
funding carried out . . . stocks will fall to 80 or even a little
less . . . I assure you that the whole of New Court as soon as they
get wind of it are going to be “bears” of millions.
4.i: The average price of 3 per cent consols,
1780-1830.

As he put it to an incredulous James: “Nathan’s
relation with these gentlemen [of the Treasury] is such as between
brothers . . . Our New Court gives me the impression of being like
a Freemasons’ lodge. He who enters becomes a Stock-mason.” The
significance of this remark will be returned to below.
In fact, the operation Vansittart mentioned to
Nathan ran into trouble because of mounting political opposition to
the Chancellor’s financial policy. Indeed, Nathan’s sale of consols
at the end of 1817 may have been one of the abuses which
Vansittart’s critics had in mind when they accused him of being “at
the Mercy of the Money Market” and fuelling “the inordinate spirit
of gambling.” Vansittart’s task was in many ways a hopeless one. As
noted in the previous chapter, the British public debt had grown to
immense proportions—£900 million, or roughly 200 per cent of
national income—as a consequence of the wars against France. But in
1815 the House of Commons defied the government by refusing to
renew the wartime income tax (and the malt tax), causing an
immediate loss of over £14 million in revenue. Faced with annual
debt service charges of over £30 million, to say nothing of the
continuing costs of the army and navy, the government had little
option but to increase indirect taxes—of which the duty on imported
corn or “Corn Law” was to become the most controversial—and to
carry on borrowing.
Vansittart’s strategy in 1818, which aimed at
concealing the extent of the deficits he was running in order to
boost consol prices, was to borrow short term by issuing exchequer
bills, in order to continue making payments to Pitt’s sinking fund.
This hand-to-mouth system undoubtedly suited those, like Nathan,
who bought and sold both bills and consols. But it was criticised,
given the inflationary consequences of issuing exchequer bills to
redeem consols, by those political economists who regarded the
continuing depreciation of paper money and the exchange rate in
terms of gold as the principal post-war problem. Led within the
government by William Huskisson and supported (after initial
doubts) by Robert Peel, the proponents of the resumption of gold or
“cash” payments by the Bank of England gradually gained the upper
hand over Vansittart and the directors of the Bank itself. With the
setting up of the “Secret Committee on the Expediency of the Bank
Resuming Cash Payments” under Peel’s chairmanship in 1819, the
“bullionists” had effectively won.8 Dismayed, Nathan sought to dissuade
Liverpool from going back on to gold, even pursuing ministers into
the country to make his case. But the Prime Minister’s mind had
been made up, as he indicated to Vansittart in October 1819:
Nothing can be more foolish than Rothschild’s
following you, and intending to follow me, into the country. If his
proceeding is known it can of course only augment the general
alarm, and increase all the evils he is desirous of preventing . .
. The point . . . upon which I feel most anxiety is the idea
suggested by Rothschild, of a continuance of the Bank restriction.
I am satisfied that no measure could be more fatal, and that the
very notion of its being a matter for consideration would do harm .
. . As to continuing the restriction from the dread of their
diminishing their [the Bank of England’s] circulation too much,
this would be a ground for perpetual restriction, and is the idea
of all others that it was most necessary to combat last year. Let
us therefore determine to stand upon our present system, and let no
one entertain a doubt that this is our determination.
Given the ultimate triumph of the gold standard in
the nineteenth century, it is easy to dismiss Nathan’s position as
special pleading. Yet Nathan’s opposition to cash payments was far
from unjustifiable, and it was an error on the part of the
bullionists and radicals to assume that he was motivated solely by
self-interest. Nathan never opposed the resumption of cash payments
as a matter of theoretical principle: he and his fellow bankers
made a practical argument that the short-run effects of a
deflationary policy would be economically destabilising, and that
this might tend to run counter to the government’s goal of fiscal
and monetary stabilisation. The Treasury official George Harrison
was right to worry in October 1818 about the consequences of
tightening monetary policy at a time when the budget remained
unbalanced. As he said to Vansittart,
Its effect upon our concerns and upon the Stocks
may be very considerable—for such a proceeding would drive . . .
our Agent [meaning Nathan] in all probability to become a
Seller of his stock . . . and would inevitably affect the Funds
more or less . . . We could not with justice or propriety be
pressing him to extend his accommodations to us, when the Bank
refused to accommodate him by Discounts—as he would then be driven
to become a Seller to a larger extent to enable him to meet our
Wants.
In fact, as we have seen, Nathan had already done
most of his selling. But his brokers and their clients felt the
effects of the government’s deflationary policies when he issued a
new loan of £12 million for the government in the summer of 1819.
The decision to stick to 3 per cents more or less precluded a rapid
rise in the new stock at a time when consol prices were already in
the doldrums not far above the issue price of 69. It was this link
between monetary tightening and the continuance of government
borrowing which he had sought to point out to Liverpool, who
preferred to believe Baring that there would soon be “a reaction”
(that is, a recovery) in consol prices. Similarly, in his evidence
to the Committee of Cash Payments in 1820, Nathan did not deny for
a moment that the depreciation of sterling and outflow of specie
into foreign bonds was due in part to the suspension of gold
payments. The key point was that the combination of tight money and
a mountainous government debt was a perilous one for the economy as
a whole:
Have the goodness to state to the Committee in
detail, what you conceive would be the consequence of an obligation
imposed upon the Bank to resume cash payments at the expiration of
a year from the present time?—I do not think it can be done
without very great distress to this country; it would do a great
deal of mischief; we may not actually know ourselves what mischief
it may cause.
Have the goodness to explain the nature of the
mischief, and in what way it would be produced?—Money will be
so very scarce, every article in this country will fall to such an
enormous extent, that many persons will be ruined.
This was no exaggeration. Events would amply
demonstrate that in embarking on monetary stabilisation before
resolving the post-war fiscal crisis, the government was sailing
into uncharted and potentially dangerous waters. As Nathan’s
brother-in-law Abraham Montefiore shrewdly observed in 1821,
defending the record of “the poor inoffensive Old Lady, Mr.
V[ansittart]”: “The only really effective plan would be a good
property tax properly and judiciously levied to reach only the
opulent and those that can afford to spare part of their income,
but unfortunately it so happens that these very persons are the
law-makers themselves and their patriotism does not go so far as to
reach their pockets.” The attempt to balance the budget with
virtually no direct taxation at a time of monetary deflation would
prove a recipe for instability.
“The Chief Ally of the Holy Alliance”
There was one obvious response to the difficulties
experienced by the Rothschilds in London and Paris between 1815 and
1819: to seek new business elsewhere. The alternative was to assist
with the financial stabilisation of the other great powers:
Austria, Prussia and Russia, now grouped together, at the Tsar’s
suggestion, as a “Holy Alliance,” as well as the various smaller
states in Italy and Germany in their respective spheres of
influence. Like France and Britain, the Central and East European
states emerged from the war with dire financial problems which
could be addressed only with the assistance of foreign capital. As
Disraeli later put it in his novel Coningsby: “[A]fter the
exhaustion of a war of twenty-five years, Europe must require
capital to carry on peace . . . France wanted some; Austria more;
Prussia a little; Russia a few millions.” Moreover, the policy of
the Holy Alliance was bound to create additional financial needs
from which the Rothschilds could also profit. For the principal aim
of the Alliance was to avert a recurrence of the revolutionary
“epidemic” which had caused such upheaval in Europe between 1789
and 1815—if necessary by military intervention. That implied
further expenditure.
The first major post-war loan which the brothers
succeeded in making was to Prussia, which had ended the Napoleonic
period with a debt burden of around 188 million thaler (£32
million) and continued to run large deficits in 1815, 1816 and
1817. Although the Frankfurt-based Rothschilds had arranged a small
Prussian loan of 5 million gulden (£450,000) in early 1817 (much of
which they placed with the Elector of Hesse-Kassel), the size of
the floating debt reached 20 million thaler by the autumn, and the
government began to contemplate raising a loan in London. The idea
for such a loan in fact originated with the representative of the
Prussian Seehandlung bank in London, a merchant named Barandon, who
came close to scuppering the entire project when he rashly
published details of Nathan’s proposed terms in January 1818. As
these were singularly tough—the issue price was to have been 60,
implying an interest rate of 8.33 per cent—they provoked an outcry
in Berlin, where the local bankers hastened to put together a
better offer. Berating Nathan for having involved Barandon, whose
reputation in Paris was that of a bankrupt small-time commodities
dealer, Salomon hastened from Paris to Koblenz for fraught talks
with the Prussian State Chancellor Hardenberg, and then proceeded
to Berlin, where he and Carl managed to undo at least some of the
damage. With the connivance of the Prussian minister in London, the
great educational and political reformer Wilhelm von Humboldt,
Barandon was quietly sidelined—though it was not until after five
days of continuous bargaining with the finance official Rother (now
Director in the new Prussian Treasury) that an agreement was
finally secured in London at the end of March.9
Historians have long claimed that the Prussian
government’s decision to raise a loan in London was intended to
avoid the need for political concessions—such as the summoning of
an assembly of the estates (Stände) or the creation of an
independent judiciary—which the recourse to domestic sources of
finance might have necessitated. However, the Rothschild
correspondence tells a different story. From the outset of the
negotiations, Nathan argued that any loan would have to be secured
by a mortgage on Prussian royal domains guaranteed by the
Stände of the domains concerned. When Hardenberg demurred,
Nathan spelt out his reasons for wishing such a guarantee in a
remarkable memorandum:
[T]o induce British Capitalists to invest their
money in a loan to a foreign government upon reasonable terms, it
will be of the first importance that the plan of such a loan should
as much as possible be assimilated to the established system of
borrowing for the public service in England, and above all things
that some security, beyond the mere good faith of the government .
. . should be held out to the lenders . . . Without some security
of this description any attempt to raise a considerable sum in
England for a foreign Power would be hopeless[;] the late
investments by British subjects in the French Funds have proceeded
upon the general belief that in consequence of the representative
system now established in that Country, the sanction of the Chamber
to the national debt incurred by the Government affords a guarantee
to the Public Creditor which could not be found in a Contract with
any Sovereign uncontrolled in the exercise of the executive
powers.
In other words, a constitutional monarchy was seen
in London as a better credit-risk than a neo-absolutist regime. Was
this a subtle form of political pressure—a kind of financial
liberalism, lending its weight at a critical time to the efforts of
the Prussian reformers who had been pressing Frederick William III
to accept some kind of system of representation? Or was Nathan
merely justifying the differential between his terms and those
obtained by France from Baring? James’s positive allusion to the
(notional) ability of French deputies to go to the Treasury and
“examine the books” suggests that the Rothschilds really did see
some kind of constitutional control over public finances as
desirable, if only as a way of reassuring British investors.
Admittedly, Nathan was prepared to settle for much less than
parliamentary control in the Prussian case: clause 5 of the final
contract merely stated that “for the security of the creditors”
there would be a special mortgage on the royal domains “which are
wholly disposable according to the House[hold] Law of November 6,
1809, passed by H. M. the King of Prussia and the princes of the
royal house with the assent of the provincial estates.” The
allusion to the estates could hardly have been more oblique. On the
other hand, the astonishing tone of some of Nathan’s letters to
Rother—especially when Rother attempted to modify the terms after
the contract had been signed—reveal his lack of respect for the
Prussian regime:
Dearest friend, I have now done my duty by God,
your King and the Finance Minister von Rother, my money has all
gone to you in Berlin . . . now it is your turn and duty to do
yours, to keep your word and not to come up with new things, and
everything must remain as it was agreed between men like us, and
that is what I expected, as you can see from my deliveries of
money. The cabal there can do nothing against N. M. Rothschild, he
has the money, the strength and the power, the cabal has only
impotence and the King of Prussia, my Prince Hardenberg and
Minister Rother should be well pleased and thank Rothschild, who is
sending you so much money [and] raising Prussia’s credit.
Moreover, Nathan’s insistence on some kind of
political guarantee had important political implications. There is
an obvious link from Nathan’s negotiations with Rother to the
subsequent Clause 2 of the “Decree for the Future Management of the
State Debt” of January 17, 1819, which imposed a ceiling on the
state debt, earmarked revenues from the royal domains to service it
and declared: “If the state should in future for its maintenance or
for the advancement of the common good require to issue a new loan,
this can only be done in consultation with, and with the guarantee
of, the future imperial estates assembly.” Drafted by Rother
himself, this meant that any future loan by the Prussian state
would automatically lead to the summoning of the estates; in other
words, it conceded the link between public borrowing and
constitutional reform. Only by raising loans indirectly through the
notionally independent Seehandlung could the Prussian state
henceforth borrow money without summoning the estates. This
explains why, of all the German states, Prussia borrowed the least
in the 1820s and 1830s and why, when the policy of retrenchment
broke down in the 1840s, the consequences were revolutionary.
Whatever its significance for Prussian politics,
the 1818 Prussian loan was without question a watershed in the
history of the European capital market, as contemporaries came to
recognise. For Nathan’s demand for some kind of political security
was, in financial terms, probably the least important of the
conditions he attached to the loan. Firstly, the loan was to be not
in thaler, but in sterling, with the interest payable (half-yearly)
not in Berlin but in London. Secondly, there was to be a
British-style sinking fund to ensure the amortisation of the loan
(though Rother managed to get rid of Nathan’s initial stipulation
that it take the form of £150,000 of British consols). This
deliberate Anglicisation of a foreign loan was a new departure for
the international capital market. The Baring French loans had paid
interest in francs in Paris, with attendant inconvenience and
exchange rate risks for British investors. Now it was much easier
to invest in foreign funds; and the fact that throughout the
century all foreign government bonds paid higher yields than
British consols meant that people did. The Times did not
exaggerate when it later described Nathan as “the first introducer
of foreign loans into Britain”:
for, though such securities did at all times
circulate here, the payment of dividends abroad, which was the
universal practice before his time, made them too inconvenient an
investment for the great majority of persons of property to deal
with. He not only formed arrangements for the payment of dividends
on his foreign loan in London, but made them still more attractive
by fixing the rate in sterling money, and doing away with all the
effects of fluctuation in exchanges.
Moreover, the loan was issued not just in London
but also in Frankfurt, Berlin, Hamburg, Amsterdam and Vienna. In
other words, it represented a major step towards the creation of a
completely international bond market. In his book On The Traffic
in State Bonds (1825), the German legal expert Johann Heinrich
Bender identified this as one of the Rothschilds’ principal
contributions to modern economic development: “Any owner of
government bonds . . . can collect the interest at his convenience
in several different places without any effort.” Henceforth, an
investor could receive the interest on Austrian metalliques,
Neapolitan rentes or any other Rothshild-issued bonds from any of
the Rothschild houses. In stipulating these conditions, Nathan not
only succeeded in making the Prussian loan attractive to British
and continental investors; he also established a model for such
international bond issues which would swiftly become
standard.10
Although the terms of the loan were heavily
criticised in Berlin (not least by the bankers there), Humboldt and
Rother were impressed. Nathan, Humboldt reported to Hardenberg, was
not only “the most enterprising businessman here”; he was also
“dependable . . . fair, very upright and understanding” in his
dealings with governments. Rother went further: “The Rothschild in
this country . . . has an incredible influence upon all financial
affairs here in London. It is widely stated, and is, indeed, close
to the truth, that he entirely regulates the rate of exchange in
the City. His power as a banker is enormous.” His reputation in
Berlin firmly established, Nathan was able to secure a second loan
(to the Seehandlung) in 1822 for £3.5 million.
In one respect, Rothschild activity in Germany was
far from innovative. Hesse-Kassel was one of those states which had
emerged intact from the Napoleonic period, and Amschel was careful
to continue cultivating the special relationship his father had
developed with the Elector. Now that he had been restored to his
lands, however, William needed the Rothschilds less, and the
family’s old rivals in Kassel hastened to reassert their influence
at court. The Rothschilds continued to manage some of the Prince’s
financial affairs, collecting his reparations from France, selling
his English stocks (as we have seen) at a healthy profit, trying to
sort out his tangled Danish investments and involving him in their
post-war loans to Prussia. Amschel even indulged his old
coin-collecting enthusiasm. But there was no doubt that the days of
mutual dependence were over, especially when Buderus had ceased to
be the dominant force in the Kassel bureaucracy. Although the
brothers lent considerable sums to William’s spendthrift son, their
hopes that these highly unprofitable transactions would bring more
lucrative business after he succeeded his father were disappointed
when this finally happened in 1821. Apart from two large loans in
1821 and in 1823 for a total of 4.3 million gulden (£390,000),
business in Kassel dried up.
On the other hand, Hesse-Kassel was only one of
thirty-nine German states which had emerged from the Napoleonic
upheaval and were now grouped together as members of the loose
German Confederation. And because the Confederation’s Diet met in
Frankfurt—in a rented hall in the Thurn und Taxis palace—it was
easy for Amschel and Carl to establish contact with senior
diplomatic representatives of all the member states. This led to a
stream of relatively small-scale loans to minor German states and
princes—including the neighbouring Grand Duchy of Hesse-Darmstadt,
as well as Schaumburg, Homburg, Saxe-Weimar, Anhalt-Coethen and
Nassau-Usingen—throughout the 1820s. Though the individual loans
only rarely exceeded 500,000 gulden (£45,000), taken together they
represented a substantial amount of business. Between 1817 and 1829
total loans of this sort by the Frankfurt house amounted to more
than 24.7 million gulden (£2.2 million). While some were little
more than personal loans to petty princes, others took more
sophisticated forms, like the Hesse-Darmstadt lottery loan of 1825,
one of many premium-bond-style loans issued in this period. On
occasion, the Rothschilds also acted as bankers to the
Confederation itself. Twenty million francs—paid by France under
the terms of the Peace of Paris for the construction of
fortifications in Germany—were deposited with the Rothschilds in
1820, pending a decision by the Confederation to proceed with
building them. Given the slowness with which such decisions were
reached in Frankfurt, this turned out to be a long-term deposit;
but it was never certain how much notice would be needed for its
withdrawal, nor indeed who had the right to request it. The
difficulties this created for the Rothschilds may explain why they
never did much to attract similar deposits.
Real power in Germany, however, lay not in
Frankfurt, but in Vienna, the capital of the Confederation’s
dominant member: and it was the Austrian court more than any other
which the Rothschilds sought to cultivate in the 1820s. As we have
seen, the Austrians had been reluctant to leave the payment of
their British subsidies to the Rothschilds in the later stages of
the war against France, preferring to deal with Viennese houses
like Arnstein & Eskeles,11 Fries & Co. and Geymüller &
Co.; they had driven hard bargains over the French reparations
payments too. Only in partnership with the Frankfurt banker Gontard
were the brothers able to handle the minor payments Austria had to
receive in the wake of the peace from Russia and Naples. But Vienna
needed cash just as badly as the other continental states if it was
to consolidate its large floating debt and stabilise its heavily
depreciated currency. Although its first major post-war loan of 50
million gulden was concluded—to Rothschild chagrin—with the
Anglo-Hanseatic Parish brothers in partnership with Baring,
Bethmann and Geymüller, it was obvious, with annual expenditure
running above 100 million Austrian gulden, that more would soon be
needed. The breakthrough came in 1820, when Salomon jointly
organised two lottery loans worth 45 million Austrian gulden (c.
£4.8 million) in partnership with David Parish—a transaction so
profitable that, despite the hostile comment it aroused, Salomon
resolved to remain in Vienna on a more or less permanent
basis.
The final coup which completed the Rothschilds’
emergence as “bankers to the Holy Alliance” came in 1822, with the
loan to Russia. Here, as in Prussia and Austria, the war had
generated acute fiscal and monetary problems: public spending had
roughly quadrupled between 1803 and 1815 as had the circulation of
paper roubles, leading to the inevitable inflation and currency
depreciation. And despite having allowed the Rothschilds to handle
so much of her wartime subsidy payments and subsequent reparations
contributions, Russia too turned first to others for assistance
with stabilisation: it was Baring and Reid, Irving who handled the
1820 loan, for example. This, however, was no great disappointment,
as the Russians at this stage were still refusing to follow the
Prussian example of issuing a loan denominated in sterling and with
interest payable in London. Two years later the Russians, like the
Austrians before them, had come round. In the summer of 1822 a loan
of £6.6 million was issued by Nathan in 5 per cent bonds priced at
77, which he had no difficulty in selling at prices of 80 and more
to his network of London brokers, led by his brother-in-law Moses
Montefiore.
Thus by the end of 1822 the Rothschilds could
justifiably be regarded as bankers to the Holy Alliance—“la haute
Trésorerie de la Sainte Alliance.” Indeed, when the itinerant
German Prince Pückler-Muskau first described Nathan in a letter to
his wife, he introduced him as “the chief ally of the Holy
Alliance.” There is unquestionably a sense in which it was the
Rothschilds who gave the alliance substance. When the Austrian
Emperor remarked to his envoy in Frankfurt that Amschel was “richer
than I am,” he was not being wholly facetious. The Times
correspondent reported from St Petersburg that the mere appearance
of James Rothschild at the bourse was expected to boost Russian
bond prices. Without the financial support which Nathan in
particular could provide, it would have been harder to make the
Austrian strategy of “policing” Europe effective in the 1820s.
Political critics of this strategy recognised this. Nathan was
caricatured as the “Hollow Alliance’s” insurance broker, helping to
prevent political fire in Europe. In 1821 he even received a death
threat because of “his connexion with foreign powers, and
particularly the assistance rendered to Austria, on account of the
designs of that government against the liberties of Europe.”
Finance and Revolution
It had, of course, been assumed by the founders of
the Holy Alliance that the best way of preventing a renewed
revolutionary upheaval in Europe would be a policy of “containment”
directed against France, the fons et origo of revolution
since 1789. While that would prove to be the right strategy later,
in 1830 and in 1848, in the 1820s it quickly had to be abandoned as
it became evident that the political order established at Vienna
could be challenged almost anywhere. When August von Kotzebue—a
minor hack reputed to be in the pay of the Tsar—was murdered in
Mannheim by a radically inclined student, Karl Sand, it suited
Metternich quite well as the pretext for a crackdown on liberal
tendencies throughout the German Confederation. Like the
assassination of the King’s nephew, the duc de Berry, in Paris in
February 1820, one death did not portend a serious revolution. But
the Cadiz mutiny by army units destined for South America that
January was the real thing, as it led not only to the reimposition
of the 1812 Cortes constitution on the Spanish King Ferdinand VIII,
but also to the imposition of the same constitution on his uncle,
Ferdinand I of Naples, just six months later. The “domino effect”
continued in August 1820, with a military revolt in Portugal. In
March 1821 there were risings by Italians in Piedmont and by Greeks
throughout the Near East. The abortive Decembrist movement in
Russia in 1824-5 was part of the same pattern: the unrest was often
led by disenchanted soldiers (the victims of post-war cuts in
defence spending), or by secret societies like the Italian
Carbonari or the Spanish Freemasons. Indeed, so widespread was the
political instability that France, the former outcast, had to be
co-opted into the counter-revolutionary coalition. The question
which came to dominate the congresses of Troppau (October to
December 1820), Laibach (January 1821) and Verona (September to
December 1822) was how far this coalition should intervene in the
affairs of other states to prevent the success of localised
revolutions. The financial question this begged, of course, was
whether or not they could afford to do so. In so far as they helped
to finance Austrian intervention in Italy and French intervention
in Spain, the Rothschilds deserve to be thought of as financiers of
“reaction.”
From the Rothschild viewpoint, however, the
instability of Restoration Europe was not only a source of
potential new business; it was also a threat to the stability of
financial markets. Existing loans to regimes which suddenly looked
vulnerable slumped as alarmed investors sought to sell their bonds.
Even successful armed intervention, by throwing the Austrian and
French budgets into deficit, had similar negative side-effects. On
the other hand, the emergence of new states in those regions where
revolutions actually succeeded created a source of new business
too. In particular, the creation of independent states in Brazil,
in formerly Spanish America and in Greece led to numerous new bond
issues as fledgling regimes rushed to the London and Paris capital
markets. For that reason, the role of the Rothschilds’ financial
power was ambivalent.
On the Italian peninsula, matters were relatively
straightforward: the Rothschilds supported Metternich’s policy of
divide and rule by lending to the various monarchical regimes which
had his backing. As early as December 1820 Metternich wrote to
Salomon from Troppau alluding suggestively to a transaction
involving 25 or 30 million francs “with respect to the future fate
of the Kingdom of Naples.” The banker’s initial response was
positive. “Even our financiers, led by Parish and Rothschild,” so
the Austrian Finance Minister Stadion assured Metternich at Laibach
in January 1821, “are only anxious to see our troops across the Po
at the earliest possible moment, and marching on Naples.”
Nevertheless, Salomon was unenthusiastic when Metternich and
Nesselrode invited him to Laibach to discuss possible loans, the
purpose of which was evidently to pay for intervention. “My
presence there,” he explained to Nesselrode, “might give rise to
numerous and probably highly inaccurate newspaper reports. Persons
with base motives might unearth the fact that a loan to the most
gracious monarchs was being discussed; rumour would be piled upon
rumour, and this would not be at all agreeable in the highest
quarters.” Firstly, the prospect of a new Austrian loan would
depress the Vienna market, already shaken by the Italian crisis.
Secondly, the Rothschilds had no desire to make their role in
financing the Holy Alliance so public. Instead, Salomon insisted to
Stadion that any loan should be raised by Ferdinand I only after
his restoration to power, the proceeds to be used to reimburse the
Austrian government for the costs of intervention. In the meantime,
he offered Stadion short-term advances to finance General Frimont’s
advance south. As in the Napoleonic Wars, the Rothschilds used
their extensive banking network to make cash available at
reasonable rates to an army on the march. And, as before, one of
the brothers—this time Carl (“un petit frère Rothschild,” as he
seemed to Stadion)—had to be sent to the scene of the action to
ensure that all ran smoothly. In March 1821 Carl set off from
Vienna to join Metternich and the exiled Neapolitan king at
Laibach.
To Metternich, the Neapolitan campaign was nothing
less than a counter-revolutionary crusade: “We have embarked,” he
told Stadion,
on a great undertaking, one that contains the
possibilities of greater results than any of our time. It is great,
for upon its success or failure the whole future depends; not
merely the future of the Austrian monarchy, but that of the whole
of Europe . . . It was impossible for us to take any other action,
for it is a matter of life or death . . . everything now depends
upon success. If not, the result will be the same as if we had
ventured nothing; the revolution will engulf first Italy and then
the world. I will spare no effort until I am killed myself.
But financial reality gave the lie to such
rhetoric. There were recurrent shortages of supplies at the front,
while in Vienna Stadion despairingly foresaw a return to the fiscal
and monetary morass of the Napoleonic period. Indeed, Salomon had
to intervene to prevent a slump in the price of “metalliques”
(Austrian silver-denominated bonds). The crisis deepened when
reports reached Laibach of further revolutionary outbreaks in
Piedmont. The impact of this news in Vienna appalled the hapless
Stadion:
If the enemy were at the gates there could not be
more unreasoning panic. The whole of the population of Vienna is
rushing to the Bourse to get rid of our public securities . . . Our
credit (which has only just been established) is on the eve of
vanishing completely. I shall be forced to suspend the conversion
of paper money into cash . . . destroying in one day the labours of
the preceding five years . . . This is the first step to our
destruction. It is impossible that a loan should be considered,
either at home or abroad, at a time when our securities are
becoming worthless.
By March 24, however, Naples had fallen, and Carl
hurried south after Ferdinand to organise the now desperately
needed loan from which the Austrians were to be reimbursed.
At this point, a conflict of interests emerged: the
Austrian government wished to exact the maximum sum possible, but
the Rothschilds had a low opinion of Neapolitan creditworthiness,
and were willing to lend to the restored regime only at punitive
rates, while the Bourbon regime itself faced the prospect of
renewed unrest if it was burdened with onerous new debts. The first
Neapolitan loan was a hard-won compromise, with Carl being forced
to improve his initial offer to head off competition from a rival
Milanese banker: instead of 10 million ducats at a discounted price
of 54, he agreed to lend the government 16 million (around £2
million) at 60. To help meet the costs of the continuing Austrian
occupation, a second loan was issued in November 1821, of 16.8
million ducats, underwritten at 67.3. Two more loans followed for
22 million ducats in 1822 and £2.5 million in 1824, increasing the
state’s debt to around £13 million in all. Nevertheless, the price
of Neapolitan securities rose in Paris from 65 to 103, and in
London there was considerable enthusiasm for the
sterling-denominated bonds. This successful stabilisation partly
reflected the good relationship which had developed between Carl
and the new Neapolitan Finance Minister, Luigi de’ Medici, whose
claim that the Austrians were unnecessarily prolonging the
occupation and overcharging for their presence Carl was inclined to
support. Even before the Congress of Verona in late 1822, it was
obvious that the Austrians intended to recoup the costs of the
invasion in full: of 4.65 million gulden which Metternich demanded
in August 1821 as payment for the actual invasion, 4 million had
been received by the following February, and to this were added
occupation costs of 9 million ducats per annum. By 1825 Medici was
accusing the Austrian government of deliberately profiting from the
occupation and threatened to resign unless more than 1 million
ducats were repaid. When the Viennese authorities stalled, Carl
advanced the money to Medici—to Metternich’s evident
irritation.12
The Austrian intervention in Naples provided a
classic illustration of the difficulty of maintaining good
relations with both sides in a bilateral international transfer.
Nevertheless, Carl had probably struck the right balance between
Austrian and Italian interests. While his establishment in Naples
flourished on the strength of his ties with the Bourbon regime (and
also did some business with the Grand Duke of Tuscany), Metternich
continued to turn to Salomon for financial assistance over other
Italian matters—notably the complicated 5 million lire loan
organised to provide for the children of the Archduchess
Marie-Louise, the Habsburg Princess who had briefly been married to
Napoleon, and who had been established after his fall in the
duchies of Parma, Piacenza and Guastalla.13 Another such case concerned the
finances of Napoleon’s former Governor in Illyria, Marshal de
Marmont, the Duke of Ragusa. At the same time, the Austrian
government found itself once again having to turn to the
Rothschilds to satisfy its own burgeoning financial needs. For no
matter how much could be squeezed out of Naples, the costs of the
military intervention there far exceeded what Stadion could raise
in current revenue. There was no alternative but another loan; and
although some officials were minded to reject the initial
Rothschild bid, the government ended up bowing to the inevitable,
although it managed to secure improved terms.14
Vienna’s dependence on the Rothschilds was further
increased in 1823, when the British government, in an attempt to
exert pressure on Vienna to end its occupation of Naples, raised
the question of outstanding loans—now notionally totalling £23.5
million including interest—which had been given to Austria in the
early stages of the war against France. Once again Austria turned
to the Rothschilds, pressing Salomon to use his brother’s influence
in London to get the debt scaled down—the first of many occasions
when the Rothschilds would act as an unofficial channel for
Metternich’s diplomatic communications. When this had finally been
achieved, the Rothschilds offered to organise yet another loan, in
partnership with Baring and Reid, Irving, to pay the agreed sum of
£2.5 million. Thirty million gulden of new metalliques were taken
by the banks at an underwriting price of 82.33, and were soon
trading at 93, yielding a substantial profit to the banks. Another
15 million gulden loan followed in 1826. Ultimately, the Austrian
policy of intervention in Italy had yielded multiple profits for
the Rothschilds.
By contrast, the outbreak of revolution in Spain
raised more serious dilemmas. For two years after 1820, the
gout-ridden despot Ferdinand VII endured the Cortes constitution,
and in that period the liberal government raised a number of loans
(which were needed to compensate for the shortfall in revenues
caused by the revolution). Although the Rothschilds—as Salomon
hastened to reassure Metternich—were not at first involved in
these, they were preparing to take a hand when, in July 1822,
Ferdinand and his Ultra-royalist supporters unexpectedly attempted
to overthrow the Cortes, calling for foreign intervention when
their coup failed. At this point James became involved in an
attempt by the Spanish financier Bertran de Lys to forestall an
invasion by reconstituting the government on less “exalted” (that
is, radical) lines.15 It was too late, however; in April
1823, a French expedition analogous to the Austrian invasion of
Naples was launched under the leadership of Louis XVIII’s surviving
nephew, the duc d’Angoulême, and with the enthusiastic support of
revanchist diplomats like the vicomte de Chateaubriand.
Ever the pragmatist—and anxious not to be
out-flanked by that seasoned military paymaster Ouvrard—James now
offered his services to the French Prime Minister, the comte de
Villèle: just as his brother had supplied the Austrian army in
Italy with cash, so he now made himself “useful” to d’Angoulême,
even raising the ransom money needed to buy Ferdinand VII’s
release.16 And just as military intervention had
necessitated a new loan in Vienna, so too in Paris the government
was obliged to fund its military adventure by borrowing: in 1823
James was at last able to overcome the suspicion of the Restoration
regime and secure a major French loan. Worth 462 million francs
(nominal) or £18.5 million, it was the biggest single issue of
rentes by a French government between 1815 and 1848 and had been
preceded by a smaller issue of 120 million in 6 per cent treasury
bills, also handled by James. Given the importance of such issues
throughout James’s long career in Paris, it is worth noting how he
pulled off this deal. Rather as his father had initially squeezed
out his rivals in Kassel, James won his first rentes issue by
outbidding Lafitte and three other Paris bankers, offering a price
(89.55) which was actually above the current market rate. This was
more than enough to beat the rival group’s offer of 87.75, but it
did not leave James out of pocket: the success of the operation
quickly pushed rentes up above 90 and by the end of 1823 they had
reached 100.
The difference between Naples and Spain was that
after the restoration of the Spanish Bourbon (which had been
achieved by the end of 1824), the Rothschilds declined—after
contemplating a joint operation with Baring and Reid, Irving—to
lend to his neo-absolutist regime without guarantees which the
French government was unwilling to give.17 There were three reasons for this: the
regime’s refusal to recognise and redeem the bonds issued by the
Cortes, its refusal to repay France the costs of the invasion and,
finally, the bankers’ suspicion that any money lent to Ferdinand
might be used in a last and probably vain attempt to recapture his
former colonies in South America, which had been fighting
successfully for their independence since 1808. After all, had not
the 1820 revolution begun with a mutiny by soldiers about to be
sent across the Atlantic? And were not Ferdinand’s advisers
convinced that recovering the American colonies would solve all his
financial problems? It was the South American dimension which
particularly concerned the British government. While London had
been prepared to put up with the French expedition into Spain,
despite its implicit negation of Wellington’s victory in the
Peninsular War, the notion that this might be the prelude to some
kind of reconquest of Latin America, with whose fledgling republics
Britain was rapidly forging close economic ties, was wholly
unpalatable. As the Austrian ambassador in Paris reported to
Metternich: “Although the House of Rothschild may pretend that
their sympathies are purely monarchist, the recognition of the
engagements entered into by the Cortes Government, and the
independence of the Spanish colonies, would provide a far wider
field for his [Nathan’s] financial enterprises and afford political
security, the value of which they do not fail to appreciate.” In
short, the Rothschild role in Spain had been ambivalent: initially
showing signs of interest in the Cortes government, then financing
the French invasion, but declining to bankroll the restored regime.
James, Salomon and Nathan all came under conflicting pressures from
the governments in Paris, Vienna and London; but the final outcome
was a united and carefully calculated policy of non-commitment,
which was continued throughout the decade. As James put it
succinctly in 1826, “Spain’s bankruptcy is uppermost in my
mind.”
The Rothschilds kept a safe distance from the
numerous bond issues by the former Spanish colonies which were
generating such speculative enthusiasm in London at the time of the
French intervention. The years 1822-4 were the time of the great
South American “bubble,” as investors rushed to lend to new
republics like Chile, Colombia, Buenos Aires and Guatemala. Even as
unlikely a figure as Gregor MacGregor, a Scottish adventurer and
former general in the Venezuelan army, was able to raise £200,000
by styling himself the “Caique of Poyais” and persuading investors
that the malarial swamp in Honduras which he claimed to rule was
ripe for development. With a bravado it is impossible not to
admire, MacGregor even wrote to Nathan outlining a project for an
independent Hebrew colony in his “kingdom” on an island called
Ruatan. From all this the Rothschilds remained aloof, with one
exception: Brazil. There were two reasons for this preference.
Firstly, Brazil remained closely linked to Portugal and therefore
enjoyed close commercial ties with Britain; secondly, it retained a
monarchical form of government even after gaining independence in
1825. (Indeed, the fact that the Brazilian Emperor was married to
an Austrian princess inclined some contemporaries to regard Brazil
as a kind of American representative of the Holy Alliance, though
this exaggerated Austrian influence.)18 Nathan’s first step in this direction
came in 1823, with a loan of £1.5 million to Portugal, secured on
Brazilian revenues. This once again demonstrated his willingness to
lend to a constitutional regime, as the Portuguese King had
accepted a Spanish-style constitution drafted by the Lisbon Cortes
on his return from Brazil in 1822. The water for Brazilian bonds
proper was tested in 1824 by a City group led by Thomas Wilson,
which sold over a million pounds’ worth of 5 per cent bonds at an
issue price of 75. When these rose to 87, Nathan took over, issuing
a further £2 million in 1825 at a price of 85. As Heinrich Heine
later joked, Nathan was now “the great Rothschild, the great Nathan
Rothschild, Nathan the Wise, with whom the Emperor of Brazil has
pawned his diamond crown.” Though it fell into disuse during the
middle decades of the century, the relationship with Brazil was to
prove one of the firm’s most enduring.
By the summer of 1825, therefore, the Rothschilds
had succeeded triumphantly in establishing themselves as the
leading specialists in European public finance—and not only
European. One by one, the powers of the Holy Alliance had followed
the British lead, entrusting their loans to Rothschilds: first
Prussia, then Austria, then Russia. Finally, France too had to
abandon her preference for more established Parisian houses. In the
space of three years, the brothers had provided the crucial
financial assistance which enabled Austria to suppress revolution
in Naples, and France to restore royal absolutism in Spain. Yet
their contemporary image as “bankers to the Holy Alliance” was in
some respects a caricature. It understated what might be called
their political agnosticism, their tendency to assess business
opportunities in financial rather than political terms. James
neatly summed up the Rothschild attitude to Restoration politics in
an exuberant letter to Nathan in late 1826:
It would be a mortal sin to be dependent on a
Villèle and on a Canning and on what these Gentlemen may wish to
say in the Chambers, as a result of which one will be unable to
sleep at night, and why so? Because they want more than they can
afford to pay and we have to thank the dear Lord that we can
extricate ourselves from this situation. What we now want to say
is, “[You want] a loan? You can have one, as much as you want, and
draw a certain profit from it. But to keep all the millions, to
that we say no!”
The attraction of counter-revolution, in other
words, was not that it restored despots, but that it generated new
financial needs. Nor were conservative regimes given preferential
treatment. As the conditions attached to the 1818 Prussian loan
show, Nathan in fact saw constitutional structures for controlling
government finance as preferable to the extravagance and
inefficiency which often characterised absolutist regimes, and
which in any case tended sooner or later to generate revolutionary
pressures. Ultimately, that was why he was unwilling to lend to
absolutist Spain without a guarantee from constitutional France.
Such views would also condition the Rothschilds’ attitude to the
increasingly reactionary drift of French policy under Charles X,
who succeeded his brother in September 1824. And if, on the other
hand, the Rothschilds preferred to lend to a constitutional
monarchy like Brazil rather than a republic like Colombia, events
would soon confirm the economic rationality of that preference.
Where Laffitte, the follower of Saint-Simon, was “truly liberal”
(in Byron’s phrase), Rothschild was more politically ambivalent, a
conditional supporter of the Holy Alliance at best.
Saving an Old Lady
If the French Prime Minister Villèle had hoped the
large 1823 loan would ultimately “free him from the hands of these
gentlemen”—meaning the Rothschilds—he quickly found himself more
firmly in their grip. The sustained rise of the rentes in 1823-4
was not so much proof of “the strength and power of France”; it was
proof that interest rates throughout Europe were falling. This
presented the Rothschilds with a new business opportunity: the
conversion of government bonds bearing higher rates of interest
into new bonds with lower rates. Though new to France, such
operations had been undertaken in Britain before (for example, in
1717 and 1748-57). Indeed, Vansittart had converted £150 million of
5 per cents into 4 per cents in 1822; and two years later a further
£75 million of 4 per cents were converted into 3.5 per cents by
Frederick Robinson, his successor. For the governments which
undertook such conversions, the benefit was obvious: the annual
burden of debt service was significantly reduced. For the
Rothschilds, the benefit was obvious too: such large-scale
operations justified fat fees. The only difficulty lay in
persuading bondholders who had enjoyed substantial capital
appreciation and wished to continue enjoying annual interest of 4
or 5 per cent to accept less. One reason for the boom in
continental and Latin American bonds between 1822 and 1824 was
precisely the refusal of British bondholders to do so. Confronted
with the option of converting their British 5 or 4 per cents or
redeeming them and reinvesting the cash in higher-yielding assets,
many did the latter, fuelling the speculative fever.
In France, when Villèle proposed to convert 2,800
million francs of 5 per cent rentes into 3 per cents issued at 75,
the bondholders’ reaction took a different form. The arguments for
conversion were the same as in England: more than a third of the
French budget was being consumed by the costs of servicing the
state’s debt and, with 5 per cents rising from 93 to a peak of 106,
the time for such an operation seemed right.19 But the proposal became mixed up with
the vexed question of compensation for losses suffered by royalist
émigrés during the Revolution and was narrowly rejected in the
Upper House following spurious claims by Chateaubriand and others
(notably financiers like Casimir Périer who had been excluded from
the deal) that it was an Anglo-Austrian racket to defraud the
humble French rentier. A second, heavily modified scheme—which
offered to convert 5 per cents on a voluntary basis in return for
tax breaks—was pushed through in 1825, but only 30 million francs’
worth of bonds were exchanged, leaving James with a substantial sum
on his hands at a time when the market price was falling. Ouvrard
later claimed that the Rothschilds had doubly insured themselves
against the possible failure of the first conversion scheme by not
only insisting on an official safety net of 100 million in treasury
bills (to be issued if the banks were left with large quantities of
rentes on their hands), but also surreptitiously selling both 5 per
cents and 3 per cents. Suspicions that the Rothschilds were cutting
their losses by selling rentes—which were justified in 182520—brought to an end the brief period of
harmonious relations with Villèle which had begun in 1823. In the
wake of the conversion fiasco, the French premier made a concerted
effort to direct government business back to James’s rivals in
Paris, organising Laffitte and the Receivers-General into a
syndicate to undertake a loan to Haiti and to issue 1,000 million
francs of 3 per cent rentes for the benefit of the dispossessed
émigrés.
Yet the reality was that the Rothschilds had
enjoyed a lucky escape. As Nathan’s well informed Times
obituarist remembered:
[H]ad it [the Villèle conversion] been carried,
the convulsion in the money markets of Europe which shortly
followed it would probably have proved fatal to him with such a
burden on his shoulders, notwithstanding all his vast resources.
Indeed, it was a common remark of his own at the time, that neither
he nor the houses engaged in the undertaking with him could have
stood the shock.21
It was indeed fortunate that Villèle’s scheme
foundered when it did. For 1825 was to be the year in which the
great speculative bubble burst on the London stock exchange. And
not only would it have been awkward for Nathan to have been left
holding millions of 3 per cent rentes at such a time; the
conversion might also have made it more difficult for his brother
James to assist him in containing the English banking crisis of
that year.
The 1825 crisis had in many ways been prophesied by
Nathan and the other opponents of the decision to resume gold
convertibility six years before. Between 1818 and 1823 the Bank of
England’s note circulation fell by around a third, a dramatic
contraction. In 1824 a temporary influx of gold generated a big
expansion in the note issue, but this was followed by an equally
sharp contraction in 1825. At the same time, though fiscal policy
was gradually being brought under control following Vansittart’s
resignation in December 1822, the enthusiasm of Huskisson at the
Board of Trade for cuts in import duties made balancing the budget
harder than it might have been. The medium-term aim of these first
steps towards free trade was to increase the volume of commercial
activity, in conformity with the principles of the political
economists; but the short-term effect was to reduce revenues. Even
with sharp cuts in expenditure, the government still found itself
having to resort to both short- and long-term borrowing. Moreover,
as Nathan complained, Huskisson’s policy was also giving rise to a
trade deficit: as he told Herries in April 1825, “The consequence
of admitting foreign goods (which had not been met by any
corresponding liberality on the other side of the water) was, that
all the gold was going out of the country. He had himself sent two
millions within the last few weeks; the funds fell rapidly, and no
advantage is gained by any human being.” It was this outflow of
gold which lay behind the sharp monetary contraction of 1825. Under
these circumstances, the high prices which had been reached on the
London stock exchange during the 1822-4 bubble could not be
sustained. In April 1825 the market began to slide. The heaviest
falls were experienced by British industrial securities and Latin
American bonds: the Brazilian bonds which Nathan had issued at 85
were down to 81.25 by July and just 56 by March of the following
year.22 But the bonds of the formerly Spanish
republics fared even worse: Mexican, Colombian and Peruvian all
fell below 20. Even the best paper—British 3 per cent consols—was
affected, falling below 75 compared with a peak of more than 97 the
previous year. Such a severe asset-price deflation was bound to
bring a banking crisis in its wake.
There is an old anecdote which describes Nathan
threatening to exhaust the Bank of England’s reserve by bringing an
immense number of small denomination notes to its counter and
demanding gold. This is another Rothschild myth which is
diametrically opposed to the truth. In fact, Nathan’s relations
with the Bank of England were close and mutually beneficial.
Beginning in the summer of 1823, when he borrowed 3 million silver
dollars to finance his first loan to Portugal, he set out to
establish a direct line of communication with the Governor with the
intention of circumventing the Bank’s established bullion brokers
Mocatta & Goldsmid. It worked, though his parallel challenge to
Mocatta & Goldsmid’s position as the East India Company’s sole
bullion brokers and his later efforts to deal directly with the
Mint were thwarted. Thereafter, Nathan’s dealings with the Bank
were regular, as he later told the 1832 Committee on the Bank
Charter (with characteristic oversimplification): “You bring in
your bank notes, they give you the gold.” Much of the time, Nathan
was a buyer or borrower of gold and silver. In December 1825,
however, it was the other way round: the Rothschilds gave the Bank
their gold, supplying the “Old Lady” of Threadneedle Street with
enough specie from the continent to avert a suspension of cash
payments. James had in fact been sending substantial quantities of
gold across the Channel since the beginning of 1825, if not
earlier. In the first week of January alone, he had sent gold worth
nearly £500,000, which he expected to “impress your Bank” (meaning
the Bank of England). By the middle of the month, he was talking
about “our old established practice” of “buy[ing] some gold
whenever we can find any.”
It was at the end of the year, however, that his
assistance mattered most. As a succession of banks stopped their
payments—six failed in London alone—the Governor of the Bank
informed the government that a suspension of cash payments might be
the only way to avert a general financial collapse, as he would be
unable to meet the demand for gold likely when exchequer bills fell
due. Liverpool and his colleagues were determined not to sanction
this, suspecting the Governor of exaggerating the shortage of
bullion to undo the work of the 1819 Committee. On the other hand,
the Bank’s reserve of coined gold which could be used
immediately was running out fast, and the Cabinet was sufficiently
alarmed at the prospect of an unauthorised suspension by the Bank
that “orders had been given to the regiment of Guards to remain in
the City in case of disturbance.” Some City insiders—notably Henry
Thornton, who was battling to rescue Williams & Co.—had already
realised that “the Jew King of the City, Rothschild” had a stock of
gold in reserve, and according to one account, “by dint of a little
persuasion and exhortation [by Alexander Baring] the Jew was
induced to bring out his gold, first charging 2½ per cent
commission, then saying he did it out of public spirit, and lastly
begging that they would never tell it or he would be besieged night
and day.”
The government, however, may have hesitated to
approach Nathan because of his well-known antipathy towards
Huskisson, whose policies, as we have seen, he held responsible for
the crisis. On December 17 - the turning point of the crisis—the
wife of Charles Arbuthnot, the Joint Secretary of the Treasury,
recorded in her diary “the detestation in which Mr Huskisson is
held in the City” as well as their “utmost contempt” for the
Chancellor, Robinson. The feeling was evidently mutual. According
to her informant, Nathan’s old friend Herries (now Financial
Secretary to the Treasury),
Mr Huskisson has done all he can also to ruin
Rothschild by spreading reports that their house was in danger,
& he made Mr Canning write to Paris to enquire into the affairs
of [Rothschild’s] brother. Ld. Granville sent his private secretary
to pump Rothschild. R found out what he was at & instantly
shewed him his accounts & proved to him that he was worth 2½
millions.
Evidently, this led to a change of heart on both
sides, which no doubt owed something to Herries’s mediation and
Huskisson’s absence: “Rothschild has made the most gigantic efforts
to assist the Bank and he told Mr Herries that, if he had been
applied to sooner, he wd. have prevented all the difficulty. As it
is, if they can hold out till Monday or Tuesday, he will have
enormous sums over in sovereigns from Paris, & the pressure
will be entirely relieved.”
Nathan had done two things that evening: firstly,
he had advised the government to intervene in the money market
itself by purchasing exchequer bills to inject liquidity into the
market; secondly, and more important, he had delivered gold to the
Bank, beginning with £300,000 of sovereigns, and continuing with
larger sums in the succeeding weeks until confidence had finally
been restored. In fact, the reserve touched its lowest level (just
over a million pounds) on December 24; however, Nathan was still
delivering gold a year later, pledging a million pounds in the
course of March 1826 and a total of £10 million by September. His
principal source was James in Paris (as he later reminded Nathan,
“I emptied my coffers for your gold”). But, as Nathan recalled,
“there was a good deal [of gold] supplied from the whole world; I
imported it, and it was imported almost from every country; we got
it from Russia, from Turkey, from Austria, from almost every
quarter in the world.” The Bank’s ledgers describe the influx of
myriad kinds of gold coin from France, Italy, Holland and
Germany.
The crisis of 1825 had come close to being another
1797 (the year when the Bank had last suspended cash payments), a
monetary crisis with the potential to destabilise the British
economy as a whole. As it was, 73 out of 770 country banks failed
and, as Huskisson himself admitted, the country came within
forty-eight hours of “putting stop to all dealings between man and
man except by barter.” Looking back in 1839, Wellington had no
doubt who had averted disaster: “Had it not been for the most
extraordinary exertions—above all on the part of old Rothschild—the
Bank must have stopped payment.” Of course, Nathan would not have
made such immense deliveries of gold without asking for a generous
commission in return. The operation has to be seen as part of his
campaign to establish himself as the dominant force in the London
bullion market. On the other hand, there is no reason why he should
have bailed out the Bank and the government free of charge, when
the crisis was so manifestly the product of policies he had advised
against. The rescue of the Bank was a remarkable achievement which
owed everything to the international nature of the Rothschilds’
operations. In effect, the brothers were establishing that system
of international monetary co-operation which would later be
performed routinely by central banks, and on which the gold
standard came to depend. Increasingly, their position in the
international bullion market was becoming as dominant as their
position in the international bond market.
Byron was therefore not far wide of the mark when
he suggested in Don Juan that Baring and Rothschild reigned
over both royalists and liberals, and that their loans could “seat
a nation or upset a throne.” He erred only in regarding the two
bankers as financial equals. In 1815 they had been. By 1825 they
were not. As early as August 1820 the Bremen delegate to the German
Confederation’s Diet in Frankfurt had a conversation with his
Austrian counterpart Count Buol which acutely identified the
unrivalled extent of the Rothschilds’ political influence in
Europe:
This house has, through its enormous financial
transactions and its banking and credit connections, actually
achieved the position of a real Power; it has to such an extent
acquired control of the general money market that it is in a
position either to hinder or to promote, as it feels inclined, the
movements and operations of potentates, and even of the greatest
European Powers. Austria needs the Rothschilds’ help for her
present demonstration against Naples, and Prussia would long ago
have been finished with her constitution if the House of Rothschild
had not made it possible for her to postpone the evil day.
The Frankfurt banker Simon Moritz von Bethmann
echoed this judgement in a letter written at around the same time:
N. M. Rothschild, who is equipped with a vulgar
talent, audacity and vanity, constitutes the centrifugal point
around which the stock exchange revolves. He alone determines the
exchange, buying and selling £100,000 each day . . . I can well
understand why the Rothschilds are such useful instruments for the
[Austrian] government.
Both men had their reasons for disliking this
phenomenon, as we shall see; but they did not exaggerate it.